Nudge citizen participation by framing mobilization information: a survey experiment in China

框架(结构) 公众参与 框架效应 公共关系 政治学 理性 中国 透视图(图形) 测量数据收集 有限理性 经济 法学 工程类 健康传播 微观经济学 人工智能 统计 结构工程 计算机科学 数学
作者
Bingsheng Liu,Sen Lin,Xiaohao Yuan,Siqi He,Jinfeng Zhang
出处
期刊:Journal of Chinese governance [Informa]
卷期号:9 (1): 78-103 被引量:7
标识
DOI:10.1080/23812346.2023.2191413
摘要

AbstractAbstractDespite many efforts to promote citizen participation, it is necessary to keep exploring more efficient mobilization ways in developing countries. From the bounded rationality perspective, the authors conducted a survey experiment in China to explore the effects of a public–personal interest frame and a gain–loss frame on citizen participation. The results revealed that emphasizing public interests attracted more citizen participation than emphasizing personal interests did, and citizens were more mobilized by losing benefits due to non-participation than they were by gaining benefits due to participation. Moreover, the public–personal frame interacted with the gain–loss frame to influence citizen participation. Specifically, people were more likely mobilized to participate by public interests than by personal interests in a gain frame but not in a loss frame. These findings contribute to the understanding of bounded rationality in citizen participation and indicate the potential of framing effect to nudge citizen participation.Keywords: Citizen participationbounded rationalityframing effectinterest framenegativity bias Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Additional informationNotes on contributorsBingsheng LiuBingsheng Liu is a research professor at the School of Public Policy and Administration at the Chongqing University.Sen LinSen Lin is a doctoral candidate at the Department of Politics at the University of Exeter.Xiaohao YuanXiaohao Yuan is a teacher at the School of Public Policy and Administration at the Chongqing University.Siqi HeSiqi He is a doctoral candidate at the School of Public Policy and Administration at the Chongqing University.Jinfeng ZhangJinfeng Zhang is an associate professor at the School of Public Policy and Administration at the Chongqing University.Notes1 Fung, “Putting the Public Back into Governance,” 513–522; Denhardt and Denhardt, “The New Public Service,” 549–559; Feeney and Welch, “Electronic Participation Technologies,” 815–833; Liu et al., “Do Citizen Participation Programs,” 341–371; Balla, “Retrofitting Leninism,” 605–606.2 Osborne et al., “A New Theory for Public Service Management,” 135–158.3 Fung, “Putting the Public Back into Governance,” 513–522.4 Beebeejaun and Grimshaw, “Is the ‘New Deal for Communities’,” 1997–2011; Graaf, “Examining Citizen Participation,” 875–881.5 Dai et al., “Exploring Key Determinants of Willingness.”6 Percy, “Citizen Participation in the Coproduction,” 431–446; Wilson, “Planning and Politics,” 242–249.7 Zhuang et al., “The Role of Stakeholders,” 47–58; Huang and Yu, “Leading Digital Technologies for Coproduction,” 513–532.8 Denhardt and Denhardt. “The New Public Service,” 549–559; Osborne, “The New Public Governance?” 377–387; Leao and Izadpahani, “Factors Motivating Citizen Engagement,” 85–103; Sjoberg et al., “The Effect of Bureaucratic Responsiveness,” 340–351; Yang et al., “Enlisting Citizens,” 400–417.9 Battaglio et al., “Behavioral Public Administration Ad Fontes,” 304–320.10 Tversky and Kahneman, “The Framing of Decisions,” 453–458; Druckman, “The Implications of Framing Effects,” 225–256.11 Zamir and Sulitzeanu-Kenan, “Explaining Self-Interested Behavior,” 579–592; Simon, “Rationality in Political-Behavior,” 45–61.12 Triandis, “Individualism-Collectivism and Personality,” 907–924; Oyserman et al., “Rethinking Individualism and Collectivism,” 3–72; Zhang and Yin, “Collaborative Cheating among Chinese College Students,” 54–69.13 Rozin and Royzman, “Negativity Bias, Negativity Dominance, and Contagion,” 296–320; James and Moseley, “Does Perfarmance Information about Public Services,” 493–511; Tversky and Kahneman, “Judgment under Uncertainty,” 1124–1131.14 Miller and Krosnick, “Threat as a Motivator of Political Activism,” 507–523; Baekgaard, “Prospect Theory and Public Service Outcomes,” 927–942.15 Zamir and Sulitzeanu-Kenan, “Explaining Self-Interested Behavior,” 579–592.16 Tversky and Kahneman, “Judgment under Uncertainty,” 1124–1131.17 Fung, “Putting the Public Back into Governance,” 513–522; Mario Ianniello et al., “Obstacles and Solutions on the Ladder of Citizen Participation,” 21–46.18 Sjoberg et al., “The Effect of Bureaucratic Responsiveness,” 340–351; Arnstein, “Ladder of Citizen Participation,” 216–224; Tai et al., “Can E-Participation Stimulate Offline Citizen Participation,” 278–296.19 Zimmerman and Rappaport, “Citizen Participation, Perceived Control,” 725–750.20 Fung, “Putting the Public Back into Governance,” 513–522; Jakobsen and Andersen, “Coproduction and Equity in Public Service Delivery,” 704–713.21 Fung, “Putting the Public Back into Governance,” 513–522; Roberts, “Public Deliberation in an Age,” 315–353; Jo and Nabatchi, “Different Processes, Different Outcomes?”22 Osborne, “The New Public Governance?” 377–387; Bingham et al., “The New Governance,” 547–558.23 Leao and Izadpahani, “Factors Motivating Citizen Engagement,” 85–103; Xu et al., “Sense of Community,” 259–271.24 Nagao and Kennedy, “The Rite to Vote,” 613–630; Yi et al., “The Influence of Religious Belief.”25 Brabham, “Motivations for Participation in a Crowdsourcing Application,” 307–328.26 Sjoberg et al., “The Effect of Bureaucratic Responsiveness,” 340–351; Jakobsen, “Can Government Initiatives Increase Citizen Coproduction?” 27–54.27 Li et al., “Analysis of Citizens’ Motivation”; Jones, “Bounded Rationality,” 297.28 Zamir and Sulitzeanu-Kenan, “Explaining Self-Interested Behavior,” 579–592; Petra et al., “Are Citizens More Negative,” 1–22.29 Simon, “Rationality in Political-Behavior,” 45–61; Tversky and Kahneman, “Judgment under Uncertainty,” 1124–1131; Kahneman, “A Perspective on Judgment and Choice,” 697–720; Montibeller and Von Winterfeldt, “Cognitive and Motivational Biases,” 1230–1251.30 Jones, “Bounded Rationality and Political Science,” 395–412.31 Thaler and Sunstein, Nudge; Button, “Bounded Rationality without Bounded Democracy,” 1034–1052.32 Oliver, “Nudging, Shoving, and Budging,” 700–714; Benartzi et al., “Should Governments Invest More in Nudging?” 1041–1055.33 Button, “Bounded Rationality without Bounded Democracy,” 1034–1052.34 See note 9 above.35 Tversky and Kahneman, “The Framing of Decisions,” 453–458; Simon, “Rationality in Political-Behavior,” 45–61.36 Tversky and Kahneman, “The Framing of Decisions,” 453–458.37 Druckman, “The Implications of Framing Effects,” 225–256.38 Levin et al., “All Frames Are not Created Equal,” 149–188.39 Olsen et al., “Green Claims and Message Frames,” 119–137; Meyerowitz and Chaiken, “The Effect of Message Framing,” 500–510; Schneider et al., “The Effects of Message Framing and Ethnic Targeting,” 256–266; Penta and Baban, “Message Framing in Vaccine Communication,” 299–314.40 Olson, The Logic of Collective Action.41 Ostrom, Governing the Commons.42 See note 11 above.43 Abu-Tayeh et al., “Exploring the Motives of Citizen Reporting Engagement,” 215–226.44 Rand and Nowak, “Human Cooperation,” 413–425.45 Yang and Ott, “What Motivates the Public?” 832–842.46 Li et al., “Analysis of Citizens’ Motivation.”47 Triandis, “Individualism-Collectivism and Personality,” 907–924; Oyserman et al., “Rethinking Individualism and Collectivism,” 3–72.48 Zhang and Yin, “Collaborative Cheating among Chinese College Students,” 54–69.49 Adres et al., “Globalization and the Retreat of Citizen Participation,” 142–152.50 Zhang and Weng, “Not All Cultural Values Are Created Equal,” 144–154; Hsu and Barker, “Individualism and Collectivism,” 695–714.51 Olsen, “Leftmost-Digit-Bias in an Enumerated Public Sector?” 365–371; Nagtegaal et al., “Designing to Debias,” 565–576.52 Stanovich and West, “Individual Differences in Reasoning,” 645–726.53 Kahneman, “A Perspective on Judgment and Choice,” 697–720.54 Tversky and Kahneman, “Judgment under Uncertainty,” 1124–1131; Evans and Stanovich, “Dual-Process Theories of Higher Cognition,” 223–241.55 Baekgaard, “Prospect Theory and Public Service Outcomes,” 927–942; Knobloch-Westerwick et al., “Confirmation Bias, Ingroup Bias,” 104–124.56 Battaglio et al., “Behavioral Public Administration Ad Fontes,” 304–320; Rozin and Royzman, “Negativity Bias, Negativity Dominance, and Contagion,” 296–320; James and Moseley, “Does Perfarmance Information about Public Services,” 493–511; George et al., “Institutional Isomorphism, Negativity Bias,” 14–28; Olsen, “Citizen (Dis)satisfaction,” 469–478.57 Gerber et al., “The Comparative Effectiveness,” 996–1011.58 Arceneaux and Nickerson, “Comparing Negative and Positive Campaign,” 54–83.59 Mann et al., “Do Negatively Framed Messages,” 3–21.60 Porumbescu et al., “Only Hearing What They Want to Hear.”61 Miller and Krosnick, “Threat as a Motivator of Political Activism,” 507–523.62 See note 15 above.63 Rand and Nowak, “Human Cooperation,” 413–425; Moore and Loewenstein, “Self-Interest, Automaticity,” 189–202.64 Hughes and Zaki, “The Neuroscience of Motivated Cognition,” 62–64.65 Metzger et al., “Social and Heuristic Approaches,” 413–439.66 Aguinis and Bradley, “Best Practice Recommendations,” 351–371.67 Liu et al., “Can Local Governments’ Disclosure,” 1–19.68 See note 46 above.69 Nabatchi et al., “Varieties of Participation in Public Services,” 766–776.70 Oyserman et al., “Rethinking Individualism and Collectivism,” 3–72.71 Tversky and Kahneman, “Judgment under Uncertainty,” 1124–1131; Meyerowitz and Chaiken, “The Effect of Message Framing,” 500–510.72 Karlsson et al., “The Ostrich Effect,” 95–115.73 See note 15 above.74 Hughes and Zaki, “The Neuroscience of Motivated Cognition,” 62–64; Metzger et al., “Social and Heuristic Approaches,” 413–439.75 See note 10 above.76 Arceneaux and Butler, “How Not to Increase Participation,” 131–139.77 Li and De Jong, “Citizen Participation in China’s Eco-City Development,” 1085–1094.78 Ajzen, “The Theory of Planned Behavior,” 179–211; Yadav and Pathak, “Determinants of Consumers’ Green Purchase Behavior,” 114–122.
最长约 10秒,即可获得该文献文件

科研通智能强力驱动
Strongly Powered by AbleSci AI
更新
大幅提高文件上传限制,最高150M (2024-4-1)

科研通是完全免费的文献互助平台,具备全网最快的应助速度,最高的求助完成率。 对每一个文献求助,科研通都将尽心尽力,给求助人一个满意的交代。
实时播报
李健应助LYHHHH涵采纳,获得10
1秒前
2秒前
叶痕TNT完成签到 ,获得积分10
3秒前
Murphy应助嗒刻采纳,获得10
4秒前
6秒前
mgr发布了新的文献求助10
6秒前
HOPO发布了新的文献求助10
6秒前
汉堡包应助HJ采纳,获得10
7秒前
djh发布了新的文献求助10
7秒前
7秒前
7秒前
DAaaaa发布了新的文献求助10
7秒前
快乐应助ziqiwang采纳,获得10
8秒前
9秒前
9秒前
9秒前
Sage完成签到 ,获得积分10
10秒前
嗯哼应助赛赛采纳,获得20
11秒前
14秒前
14秒前
缺粥发布了新的文献求助10
14秒前
14秒前
MOD发布了新的文献求助10
14秒前
HOPO完成签到,获得积分10
15秒前
打打应助哥屋恩采纳,获得10
15秒前
16秒前
咩咩茶发布了新的文献求助10
17秒前
学术垃圾发布了新的文献求助10
19秒前
MOD完成签到,获得积分10
19秒前
LWC012766完成签到,获得积分10
19秒前
可爱的函函应助qingzhou采纳,获得10
20秒前
lililil完成签到,获得积分20
21秒前
李健应助DAaaaa采纳,获得10
22秒前
Bethune完成签到 ,获得积分10
23秒前
C洛7发布了新的文献求助10
24秒前
25秒前
chenpeio发布了新的文献求助10
25秒前
orixero应助敏感的盼夏采纳,获得10
26秒前
今天你学习了嘛完成签到,获得积分10
28秒前
头发很多完成签到,获得积分20
29秒前
高分求助中
Evolution 10000
юрские динозавры восточного забайкалья 800
English Wealden Fossils 700
Mantiden: Faszinierende Lauerjäger Faszinierende Lauerjäger 600
Distribution Dependent Stochastic Differential Equations 500
A new species of Coccus (Homoptera: Coccoidea) from Malawi 500
A new species of Velataspis (Hemiptera Coccoidea Diaspididae) from tea in Assam 500
热门求助领域 (近24小时)
化学 医学 生物 材料科学 工程类 有机化学 生物化学 物理 内科学 纳米技术 计算机科学 化学工程 复合材料 基因 遗传学 催化作用 物理化学 免疫学 量子力学 细胞生物学
热门帖子
关注 科研通微信公众号,转发送积分 3157519
求助须知:如何正确求助?哪些是违规求助? 2808909
关于积分的说明 7879293
捐赠科研通 2467387
什么是DOI,文献DOI怎么找? 1313431
科研通“疑难数据库(出版商)”最低求助积分说明 630398
版权声明 601919