Demystifying the Chinese Housing Boom

繁荣 经济 环境科学 环境工程
作者
Hanming Fang,Qi Gu,Wei Xiong,Lian Zhou
出处
期刊:Nber Macroeconomics Annual [The University of Chicago Press]
卷期号:30 (1): 105-166 被引量:174
标识
DOI:10.1086/685953
摘要

Previous articleNext article FreeDemystifying the Chinese Housing BoomHanming Fang, Quanlin Gu, Wei Xiong, and Li-An ZhouHanming FangUniversity of Pennsylvania and NBER Search for more articles by this author , Quanlin GuGuanghua, School of Management, Peking University Search for more articles by this author , Wei XiongPrinceton University and NBER Search for more articles by this author , and Li-An ZhouGuanghua, School of Management, Peking University Search for more articles by this author University of Pennsylvania and NBERGuanghua, School of Management, Peking UniversityPrinceton University and NBERGuanghua, School of Management, Peking UniversityPDFPDF PLUSFull Text Add to favoritesDownload CitationTrack CitationsPermissionsReprints Share onFacebookTwitterLinked InRedditEmailQR Code SectionsMoreThere have been growing concerns across the global economic and policy communities regarding the decade-long housing market boom in China, which has the second largest economy in the world, and has been the major engine for global economic growth during the past decade. News in recent months seems to suggest that the housing boom might be slowing down. A main concern is that a housing market meltdown might severely damage the Chinese economy, which in turn might generate contagious effects across the world and slow down the fragile global economy that has just emerged from a series of crises that originated in the United States and Europe. In particular, critics are concerned that soaring housing prices and the enormous construction boom throughout the country might cause China to follow in the footsteps of Japan, which had an economic lost decade after its housing bubble burst in the early 1990s.How much have housing prices in different Chinese cities appreciated during the last decade? Did the soaring prices make housing out of the reach for typical households? How much financial burden did households face in buying homes? Addressing these questions is crucial for systematically assessing the risk to the Chinese economy presented by its housing market. We address these questions by taking advantage of a comprehensive data set of mortgage loans issued by a major Chinese commercial bank from 2003 to 2013. Specifically, we construct a set of housing price indices for 120 major cities in China, which allows us to evaluate housing price fluctuations across these cities, in conjunction with the growth of households’ purchasing power and stock price fluctuations. The detailed mortgage data also allow us to analyze the participation of low-income households in housing markets and the financial burdens faced by low-income home buyers.Due to the nascent nature of the Chinese housing market, there are relatively few repeat home sales available for building Case-Shiller type repeated sales housing indices. Instead, we take advantage of the large number of new housing developments in each city and build a housing price index for the city based on sales over time of new homes within the same developments, which share similar characteristics and amenities. Consistent with casual observations made by many commentators, our price indices confirm enormous housing price appreciation across China in 2003–2013. In first-tier cities, which include the four most populated and most economically important metropolitan areas in China—Beijing, Shanghai, Guangzhou, and Shenzhen—housing prices had an average annual real growth rate of 13.1% during this decade. Our sample also covers 31 second-tier cities, which are autonomous municipalities, provincial capitals, or vital industrial/commercial centers, and 85 other third-tier cities, which are important cities in their respective regions. Housing prices in second-tier cities had an average annual real growth rate of 10.5%; third-tier cities had an average annual real growth rate of 7.9%. These growth rates easily surpass the housing price appreciation during the US housing bubble in the first decade of the twenty-first century and are comparable to that during the Japanese housing bubble in the 1980s.Despite the enormous price appreciation, the Chinese housing boom is different in nature from the housing bubbles in the United States and Japan. Our analysis offers several important observations that are useful for understanding the Chinese housing boom. First, as banks in China imposed down payments of over 30% on all mortgage loans, banks are protected from mortgage borrowers’ default risk even in the event of a sizable housing market meltdown of 30%. This makes a USstyle subprime credit crisis less likely in China.Second, while the rapid housing price appreciation has been often highlighted as a concern for the Chinese housing market, the price appreciation was accompanied by equally spectacular growth in households’ disposable income—an average annual real growth rate of about 9.0% throughout the country during the decade, with the exception of a lower average growth rate of 6.6% in the first-tier cities. This joint presence of enormous housing price appreciation and income growth contrasts the experiences during the US and Japanese housing bubble. Even during the Japanese housing bubble in late 1980s, the Japanese economy was growing at a more modest rate than that of China. The enormous income growth rate across Chinese cities thus provides some assurance to the housing boom and, together with the aforementioned high mortgage down-payment ratios, renders the housing market an unlikely trigger for an imminent financial crisis in China.Third, despite the enormous housing price appreciation over the decade, the participation of low-income households in the housing market remained stable. Specifically, we analyze the financial status of mortgage borrowers with incomes in the bottom 10% of all mortgage borrowers in each city for each year. By mapping the incomes of these marginal home buyers into the income distribution of the urban population in the city, we find that they came from the low-income fraction of the population, roughly around the 25th percentile of the distribution in the first-tier cities and around the 30th percentile in the second-tier cities.Fourth, while these low-income home buyers were not excluded from the housing market, they did endure enormous financial burdens in buying homes at price-to-income ratios of around eight in second- and third-tier cities and, in some years, even over 10 in first-tier cities. In concrete terms, this means that a household paid eight times its annual disposable income to buy a home. In order to obtain a mortgage loan, it had to make a down payment of at least 30%, and more typically 40%, of the home price, which was equivalent to 2.4 times to 3.2 times the household’s annual income. Suppose that the household made a down payment of 40% and took a mortgage loan for the other 60% of the home price, which would be 4.8 times its annual income. A modest mortgage rate of 6%, which is low relative to the actual rate observed during the decade, would require the household to use nearly 30% of its annual income to pay for the interest on the mortgage loan. Furthermore, paying the mortgage would consume another 16% of its annual income using a linear amortization, even if the mortgage had a maximum maturity of 30 years. Together, buying the home entailed saving 3.2 times the annual household income to make the down payment and another 45% of its annual income to service the mortgage loan.To explain the willingness of households to endure such severe financial burdens for a home, it is important to take into account the households’ expectations. To the extent that urban household income in China has been rising steadily during the studied period, as well as in the previous two decades, many households may expect their income to continue growing at this rate. At a 10% nominal income growth rate, a household’s income in five years would grow to 1.6 times of its initial income and the ratio of current housing price to its future income in five years would drop to five. Thus, a high expected income growth rate renders the aforementioned financial burdens temporary.Such high income growth expectations might have resulted from extrapolative behavior as emphasized by Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998) and Shiller (2000), or from contagious social dynamics between households as modeled by Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2013). Recently, Pritchett and Summers (2014) examined historical data on growth rates and demonstrated that regression to the mean is the single-most robust and empirically relevant fact about cross-country growth rates. Thus, they argue that while China might continue to grow for another two decades at a 9, or even a 7 or 6% rate, such continued rapid growth rate would be an extraordinary event, given the powerful force of regression to the mean, which had averaged 2% in the cross-country data with a standard deviation of 2%. If so, the high expectation of future income growth, which might have been a key driver of the observed enormous price-to-income ratios, may not be sustainable and thus presents an important source of risk to the housing market. When China’s growth rate eventually regresses to the mean, and especially when China experiences a sudden stop, households’ expectations may crash. In such a case, the large price-to-income ratios have substantial room to contract, which in turn could act as an amplifier of the initial shock that triggers the economic slowdown.Frictions in the Chinese financial system might also have contributed to the high housing prices across Chinese cities, as reflected by the large price-to-income ratios endured by households. It is well known that the spectacular economic growth in China since the 1980s has been accompanied by a high savings rate (e.g., Yang, Zhang, and Zhou 2013). Due to stringent capital controls, savers cannot invest their savings in international capital markets and, instead, have only a few domestic investment vehicles. Bank deposit accounts have remained the predominant investment vehicle, with assets totaling near 100 trillion RMB in 2013, despite the fact that the real one-year deposit rate averaged only 0.01% in 2003–2013. While the Chinese stock market experienced dramatic growth during this decade, it was still relatively small, with a capitalization of slightly less than 20 trillion RMB in 2013. The size of bond markets was even smaller. Facing this largely constrained investment set, it has been common for households to treat housing as an alternative investment vehicle, which also helps explain their willingness to pay dearly for housing.From an investment perspective, it is interesting to note a tale of two markets at the time of the world economic crisis in 2008–2009. During this period, the Chinese economy faced tremendous pressure. Nevertheless, the housing market in China remained strong. Housing prices in first-tier cities suffered a modest drop of about 10%, and recovered more than the loss shortly after the crisis. Housing prices in second- and third-tier cities continued to rise throughout the period after 2008. This experience was in sharp contrast to the dramatic decline of over 60% in the Chinese stock market in 2008—which has not recovered, even to date. To understand this puzzling contrast, we argue that the frequent policy interventions by the central government and the heavy reliance of local governments on land sales revenue for their fiscal budget might have emboldened many households to believe that the housing market is too important to fall and that the central government would institute policies to support the housing market if necessary.There are divergent views about the Chinese housing boom. Chow and Niu (2014) use a simultaneous equations framework to analyze the demand and supply of residential housing in urban China in 1987–2012 and find that the rapid housing price growth can be well explained by the force of demand and supply, with income determining demand and construction costs affecting supply. Deng, Gyourko, and Wu (2014a) are far more concerned by the risk in the Chinese housing market. In particular, they present evidence of a rapid increase in housing supply and housing inventory held by developers in various major cities in recent years. Different from these studies, we provide an informed account of the demand side by thoroughly analyzing characteristics of mortgage borrowers. Our analysis leads us to take a more balanced stand between these two contrasting views. On the comforting side, the rapid income growth, which accompanied the enormous housing price appreciation, helped support the steady participation by low-income households in the housing market. On the concerning side, high expectations about future income growth might have motivated low-income households to buy homes by undertaking substantial financial burdens, causing them to be particularly vulnerable to future sudden stops in the Chinese economy.This paper is organized as follows. Section I briefly describes some institutional background. We introduce the housing price indices in Section II and then discuss the housing price boom across three tiers of cities in Section III. Section IV summarizes characteristics of mortgage borrowers, and Section V discusses housing as an investment vehicle. Section VI provides some conceptual discussion. We summarize the role of government in Section VII and discuss several sources of risk in Section VIII.I. Institutional BackgroundThe development of housing markets in mainland China is a relatively new phenomenon. From the 1949 founding of the People’s Republic of China to 1978, all land was publicly owned and the Chinese constitution prohibited any organization or individual from buying, selling, leasing, or transferring land. Housing was allocated through a working unit-employee linkage as a form of in-kind compensation, with the size and location of homes depending on the length of employment and the size of the household, among other factors. In 1978, per capita residential area in urban areas was 3.6 square meters, which was even lower than that in 1949.To reform (and to a large extent privatize) the state-owned enterprises in the mid-1980s, it was considered necessary to introduce an alternative housing system that would delink home allocation from employment. An important milestone occurred in 1988 when the Chinese constitution was amended to allow for land transactions, which set the legal stage for the privatization of housing in China.1Comprehensive housing reform was initiated in 1994 when employees in the state sector were allowed to purchase full or partial property rights to their current apartment units at subsidized prices. Nascent markets for homes, known as “commodity houses,” emerged in some large cities in the early 1990s, but they grew rapidly only after 1998 when the central government completely abolished the traditional model of housing allocation as an in-kind benefit and privatized housing properties of all urban residents.Also in 1998, partly as a response to the adverse effects of the 1997 Asian Financial Crisis, the Chinese government established the real estate sector as a new engine of economic growth. As an important impetus to the development of private housing markets, China’s central bank, the People’s Bank of China (PBC), outlined the procedures for home buyers to obtain residential mortgages at subsidized interest rates in 1998.2 Moreover, between 1998 and 2002, the PBC lowered the mortgage interest rate five times to encourage home purchases. By 2005, China had become the largest residential mortgage market in Asia. According to a PBC report published in 2013, financial institutions made a total of 8.1 trillion RMB in mortgage loans in 2012, accounting for 16% of all bank loans in that year. At the same time, the PBC also developed policies to encourage housing development, including broadening the scope of development loans and allowing presales by developers.These policies were effective in stimulating both the demand and supply of residential housing. During this period, home sales maintained about 15% of annual growth on average, and areas of residential housing under construction grew even faster, reaching about 18% of annual growth. Figure 1 provides a rough estimate of the supply of newly completed residential housing from 2002 to 2013 by city tier, measured by completed areas in each city and each year divided by the city’s urban population in 2012.Fig. 1. Per capita area of newly built residential housingNote: For each tier of cities, we divide its annual flow of newly constructed residential housing, measured in square meters, by its urban population in 2012. The National Bureau of Statistics provides annual city-level data on space of newly constructed residential housing from 2002 to 2013 and resident population from 2005 to 2012, for 35 large cities only. These cities include all four tier-one cities: Beijing, Shanghai, Guangzhou, and Shenzhen. The other 31 cities all belong to the tier-two cities defined in the paper. We use the aggregate of these 31 cities to compute the per capita area built for tier-two cities. We then subtract these 35 cities from the national aggregates on newly constructed urban housing and urban population to get measures for tier-three (and other) cities. Resident population includes all people residing six months or more in the area governed by the city in the current year (in contrast to the hukou population). We assume all resident populations in tier-one and tier-two cities are urban, which leads to a slight overestimation of urban population in tier-one and tier-two cities and, consequently, a slight underestimation of urban population in tier-three (and other) cities. In 2012, China had a total population of 13.5 billion, out of which 7.2 billion are urban and 6.3 billion are rural. Out of those 7.2 billion who live in cities, 0.7 billion reside in tier-one cities, 2.4 billion in tier-two cities, and 4.1 billion in tier-three cities by our baseline calculation.View Large ImageDownload PowerPointIt is common in China to separate cities into three tiers. The first tier includes the four cities with the largest population and economic importance in China—Beijing, Shanghai, Guangzhou, and Shenzhen. Our data cover all of these first-tier cities. The second tier is comprised of Tianjing and Chongqing (the two autonomous municipalities other than Beijing and Shanghai) and capital cities of the 24 provinces3 and nine other cities, which are typically vital industrial or commercial centers. Our data cover 31 of these 35 second-tier cities. There is not a commonly used list for third-tier cities. Instead, we group 85 other cities in our sample as the third tier. Appendix B provides a list of all cities in our sample.The construction boom of residential housing in first-tier cities started in the late 1990s, followed by that of second- and third-tier cities early in the twenty-first century. In figure 1, new construction of residential housing showed a similar growth rate across the three tiers of cities in 2002–2005. From 2005, the new construction in first-tier cities had slowed down substantially due to the shortage of land supply in these cities, while the supply in second- and third-tier cities continued to grow at similar rates as before. The growth rate in third-tier cities was especially strong. Some estimates suggest that investment in residential housing accounted for 25% of total fixed-asset investment and contributed to roughly one-sixth of China’s gross domestic product (GDP) growth (Barth, Lea, and Li 2012).The development of the housing market was also accompanied by an urbanization process throughout China with rural migrants moving into cities, especially into first- and second-tier cities. As shown by figure 2, the total population of the four first-tier cities, the vast majority of which lived inside the city proper, grew from 48 million in 2004 to almost 70 million in 2012. The total population of the second-tier cities, which is distributed roughly half inside the city proper and half outside, grew from 220 million in 2004 to about 260 million in 2012. The total population of third-tier cities remained stable in this period at around 370 million, among which only 100 million lived inside the city proper.Fig. 2. Population in three tiers of citiesNote: There are two lines in each panel. The solid line depicts the total population within the jurisdiction of each tier of cities, while the dashed line depicts the population within the city proper of each tier.View Large ImageDownload PowerPointII. Constructing a Chinese Housing Price IndexTo systematically examine the housing market boom, it is important to construct an accurate housing price index for major cities in China. The difficulty in constructing a housing price index arises because a good price index requires that we compare the prices of the same (or at least comparable) houses over time. To the extent that the set of homes involved in the transactions in different periods of time is likely to be different, a price index constructed by simply comparing the mean or median sale prices per square meter likely measures not only the changes in the prices of similar homes, but also the changes in the composition of transacted homes. This problem is likely to be more severe in emerging housing markets than in mature ones because in emerging housing markets, homes in more central locations are likely to be built and transacted earlier than homes in the outer rings of cities.A. Standard MethodologiesThere are two standard methodologies that are widely used to construct housing price indices. These methods, which we review briefly below, are aimed at finding a suitable way to compare the prices of similar homes.One prominent approach for constructing housing prices is to use hedonic price regressions, which goes back to Kain and Quigley (1970). In this approach, the sales price is regressed on a set of variables that characterize the housing unit—number of rooms, square feet of interior space, lot size, quality of construction, condition, and so forth. The regression coefficients can be interpreted as prices for implicit attributes. This hedonic approach can then be used to construct a price index in two ways (Case and Shiller 1987). The first way to construct a price index is to run separate regressions on data from each time period. The estimated equations are then used to predict the value of a standard unit in each period, which is in turn used to construct the housing price index for the standard unit. A second way is to run a single regression on the pooled data from sales in all time periods. Inclusion of a time dummy for the period of the sale allows the constant term to shift over time, reflecting movement in prices, again controlling for characteristics.Whether hedonic price regressions can accurately capture price movements crucially depends on how well the data capture the actual characteristics and quality of the unit. Unobserved and time-varying characteristics that are valued by the market but not captured in the data can lead to biased estimates of the housing price index. This is a particular issue in China. Due to the rapid expansion of Chinese cities, new housing units have been constructed mostly on land near the urban fringes. According to the China Urban Statistical Yearbook (published by Ministry of Housing and Urban-Rural Development), the total size of developed urban area at the national level increased from 19,844 square kilometers in 2003 (Form 3–9, p. 107) to 34,867 square kilometers in 2013 (Form 2–12, p. 90). Such a dramatic expansion of urban residential land parcels implies that unobserved time-varying characteristics as transacted homes move from locations closer to city center to locations in city fringe is likely to lead to biased housing price indices.Case and Shiller (1987, 1989) popularized another method using repeated sales. This approach originated with Baily, Muth, and Nourse (1963), who initially proposed a method involving a regression where the i-th observation of the dependent variable is the log of the price of the i-th house at its second sale date minus the log of its price on its first sale date. The independent variables consist of only dummy variables, one for each time period in the sample, except for the first (the base period for the index).4 The estimated coefficients are then taken as the log price index. This initial method builds on a strong assumption that the variance of the error term is constant across houses. As this variance is likely to depend on the time interval between sales, Case and Shiller (1987) proposed a weighted-repeated-sales method with a two-step procedure to relax this assumption.5The repeat sales approach does not require the measurement of quality; it only requires that the quality of individual units in the sample remain constant over time. However, it is well recognized that this repeated sales method wastes a large fraction of transactions data because repeated sales may contribute to only a small fraction of all housing transactions. More im
最长约 10秒,即可获得该文献文件

科研通智能强力驱动
Strongly Powered by AbleSci AI
更新
大幅提高文件上传限制,最高150M (2024-4-1)

科研通是完全免费的文献互助平台,具备全网最快的应助速度,最高的求助完成率。 对每一个文献求助,科研通都将尽心尽力,给求助人一个满意的交代。
实时播报
zwh完成签到,获得积分10
刚刚
jian完成签到 ,获得积分10
刚刚
1秒前
1秒前
酷波er应助阳光的日记本采纳,获得10
2秒前
2秒前
ddak完成签到,获得积分10
2秒前
土豪的灵竹完成签到 ,获得积分10
3秒前
3秒前
adagio发布了新的文献求助10
4秒前
笨笨凡之完成签到,获得积分10
4秒前
LAVINE完成签到,获得积分20
4秒前
5秒前
lxt完成签到 ,获得积分10
6秒前
yyauthor完成签到,获得积分10
6秒前
打打应助王木木采纳,获得10
6秒前
访云完成签到 ,获得积分10
6秒前
大意的乐菱完成签到,获得积分20
7秒前
PABLO完成签到,获得积分20
7秒前
7秒前
8秒前
8秒前
大模型应助WTT采纳,获得10
9秒前
情怀应助孙伟健采纳,获得10
9秒前
奋斗蚂蚁发布了新的文献求助10
10秒前
10秒前
LL完成签到,获得积分10
10秒前
link171完成签到,获得积分10
10秒前
赵珊发布了新的文献求助30
10秒前
邵孤丝完成签到,获得积分20
11秒前
yyhgyg发布了新的文献求助10
11秒前
12秒前
12秒前
乐乐应助涛哥采纳,获得10
12秒前
单薄西装发布了新的文献求助30
13秒前
秀丽安波完成签到,获得积分10
13秒前
希望天下0贩的0应助ryt采纳,获得30
13秒前
Zhoujian发布了新的文献求助10
14秒前
岑南珍发布了新的文献求助20
14秒前
英俊的铭应助尼禄采纳,获得10
14秒前
高分求助中
Sustainability in Tides Chemistry 2800
The Young builders of New china : the visit of the delegation of the WFDY to the Chinese People's Republic 1000
Rechtsphilosophie 1000
Bayesian Models of Cognition:Reverse Engineering the Mind 888
Le dégorgement réflexe des Acridiens 800
Defense against predation 800
Very-high-order BVD Schemes Using β-variable THINC Method 568
热门求助领域 (近24小时)
化学 医学 生物 材料科学 工程类 有机化学 生物化学 物理 内科学 纳米技术 计算机科学 化学工程 复合材料 基因 遗传学 催化作用 物理化学 免疫学 量子力学 细胞生物学
热门帖子
关注 科研通微信公众号,转发送积分 3135677
求助须知:如何正确求助?哪些是违规求助? 2786507
关于积分的说明 7777976
捐赠科研通 2442633
什么是DOI,文献DOI怎么找? 1298612
科研通“疑难数据库(出版商)”最低求助积分说明 625205
版权声明 600847